Discussion about this post

User's avatar
Benjamin Cole's avatar

In San Francisco, for example, we found that while the median expectation for annual home price increases over the next 10 years was only 5 percent, a quarter of the respondents said they thought prices would increase each year by 10 percent or more. That would mean a net 150 percent increase in a decade. These people are apparently not thinking about the supply response that so big a price increase would generate.--Shiller

This is an astonishing comment to make.

Oh, maybe those city residents knew exactly what the supply response would be. You see, they were there, on the ground in SF, while Shiller was pontificating from New Haven.

I sometimes think the words "structural impediments" have been banished from the macroeconomics profession. Theory is so much more fun.

The nice thing about macroeconomic theoretical debates is no one is ever wrong.

Expand full comment
Ed in Austin's avatar

Interesting stuff!

Being in land development I always start there and try to move out. Austin where I live and do some business seems like a reasonable example. This is simple, but indicative:

+ Revenue

Units X $/Unit

- Construction costs

- Operating Costs

- Financing Costs

Equity

Debt

- Land

= Profit

If developer profit goes up, you can be sure that landowners and contractors grab a share. Using a little algebra one can move the items to one side of the = sign or the other.

All theory aside what happened in Austin is construction costs were low from the Great Recession, density (the number of units per project) increased, rent per unit increased, financing costs decreased, and exit cap rates decreased. The intermediate result was developer profits soared.

Next land prices and construction prices rose, cap rates stayed the same, financing costs stayed the same, developers could still push rents, and profits continued to be high. Basically, rents covered the new costs.

Land prices and construction costs continued to rise, cap rates stayed low, and the ability to push rents kept profits up. Land and construction could not continue to rise unless cap rates stayed low and rents rose. Construction would have stopped.

The interesting, maybe crazy, thing is that in the city limits Austin added 60,000 additional households making over $150,000, roughly twice the previous median, in the 5-year period from the of 2017 through 2022. The median income increased by $20,000 during that period. The ability to push rents based on the incomes of the additional households played a big part in what happened.

I don't think it was agglomeration or productivity. It seems like development fundamentals, demographics, and the Fed. I guess agglomeration could have caused the 60,000 households to show up, but that seems like reaching. The Pandemic is more likely.

My hunch and it's only a hunch is all of this is now baked into the cost structure (and rent structure) here and without a major economic event it will not change. It may move a few points, but Austin will stay high-cost which means it will stay high-rent.

Kinda seems like a chicken and egg thing.

Expand full comment
5 more comments...

No posts